Portuguese, Stateless Embassies
A ascensão e a queda do petismo

As próximas horas definem o rito da saída da Presidente Dilma Rousseff do cargo (a votação posterior no Senado, se necessária, será apenas pro forma), mas o domínio político do Partido dos Trabalhadores no Brasil chegou ao fim. O resultado da votação do impeachment é pouco importante: nós já sabemos que Dilma não tem mais qualquer legitimidade para permanecer no governo e que o projeto nacional-desenvolvimentista do PT acabou.

Existe uma tentação a atribuir a implosão do governo Dilma a circunstâncias contingenciais, como à inabilidade política da gerentona — burocrata de carreira, sem ligação com movimentos sociais, incapaz das mais simples conciliações de interesses dentro do estado. Mas o fracasso do PT foi construído ao longo de mais de uma década, remontando ao período anterior às eleições de 2001 que colocaram Lula na presidência.

Apesar de sua presença no imaginário popular como um partido essencialmente socialista, o PT era uma colcha de retalhos de tendências e movimentos sociais que buscavam uma voz política. A partir dos anos 1990, os movimentos que formavam a tendência majoritária do partido (encabeçada pela Articulação) haviam chegado a um consenso que buscava construir um capitalismo “disciplinado”. Em 1993, a Odebrecht começou a apoiar o PT, abrindo as portas do partido para a aliança com o empresariado brasileiro. Ao final dos anos 1990, os sindicatos que formam a base do PT já tinham ocupado a gerência dos grandes fundos de pensão brasileiros, que foram usados para “privatizar” as empresas estatais brasileiras durante a administração de FHC. Em 2001, esses fundos já desempanhavam um papel fundamental na economia brasileira, controlando na prática as grandes empresas públicas e os monopólios privados criados pelas privatizações.

Quando da eleição de Lula, o projeto petista consistia essencialmente numa aliança fascista entre a elite empresarial brasileira, a elite sindical e os caciques políticos. Tratava-se de um corporativismo leninista, onde o estado controlava a maior parte dos recursos, os distribuindo entre as elites representantes de cada classe e controlando com mão de ferro as dissidências. O modelo que fazia os olhos da cúpula petista brilhar era a China.

Até o final do governo Lula, o arranjo pareceu funcionar. O Brasil fez o caminho reverso dos anos 1990, fechando a economia para o mercado externo e passando a subsidiar fortemente as empresas nacionais (através, principalmente, do BNDES), fazendo empréstimos a baixos juros para financiar grandes fusões, criando megamonopólios dentro do país (os chamados “campeões nacionais”, e.g.: BRF, Fibria, Oi, JBS Friboi). O agronegócio também se tornou aliado do governo, que financiava sua expansão interna enquanto protegia os latifundiários da competição externa. Os altos preços das commodities agrícolas nos anos 2000 sustentaram grande parte do crescimento brasileiro na era Lula. Os movimentos sociais que tinham voz dentro do PT (como o Movimento dos Sem Terra e as centrais sindicais como a CUT) apaziguavam quaisquer descontentamentos com o acordo.

Como John Kenneth Galbraith, o PT chegou à conclusão de que somente uma economia baseada em grandes conglomerados controlados parcialmente por cada casta social (trabalhadores, empresários, políticos) seria capaz de trazer crescimento e ganhos para todos.

É assim que opera o fascismo: pretende de união do tecido social nacional, mas a única forma de fazer isso é esmagando as dissidências. A ideia metafísica de nação é a justificativa para a união de cada classe; as classes sociais, contudo, são representadas por sua elite. No caso brasileiro, a voz dos trabalhadores era ouvida através dos burocratas sindicais — que, no governo do PT, ganharam trânsito livre para negociar com grandes empresários e velhos políticos.

Quando o inchaço estatal começou a pesar demais, a dívida pública se tornou insustentável e o crescimento se esfarelou, a faceta autoritária do estado corporativo petista começou a aparecer. Vimos a remoção violenta de favelas para as obras da Copa do Mundo e das Olimpíadas, a utilização do exército para contenção de protestos, a ocupação de favelas pelos militares, a expansão indefinida do estado policial brasileiro — com um aumento da população prisional de 7% ao ano, prendendo primordialmente pessoas negras e pobres.

A política durante os 14 anos de PT no Brasil não foi acaso: não foi desvio, não foi uma guinada à direita após a chegada ao poder. O projeto era esse. Lula trabalhou diligentemente na consolidação do estado corporativo brasileiro. Seu projeto foi continuado por Dilma Rousseff. Hoje, é um programa falido — ele não apenas não é capaz de gerar crescimento, como permitiu a existência dos gigantescos esquemas de corrupção investigados pela Operação Lava Jato que ameaçam levar Lula para a cadeia.

O maior símbolo dos anos PT no Brasil é a hidrelétrica de Belo Monte. Sua construção, por um consórcio formado pela Odebrecht, Camargo Corrêa e Andrade Gutierrez, ofereceu condições de trabalho precárias e insalúbres para os operários do local por muito tempo. Os trabalhadores não eram representados no sindicato, que era controlado pelo governo. Quando os trabalhadores entraram em greve por melhores condições de trabalho, o sindicato pelego negociou prontamente um fim da paralisação junto ao consórcio. A imagem é perfeita: os trabalhadores reais contra o bloco formado por sindicatos, empresas e governo.

Antes da construção de Belo Monte, quando Dilma era apenas uma ministra, lideranças populares do Xingu foram recebidas no Planalto para exporem suas preocupações com o projeto da hidrelétrica. Irritada com as objeções, Dilma Rousseff deu um murro na mesa, gritando: “Belo Monte vai sair!“.

Hoje, quando for votado o impeachment da presidente, lembre-se de que nada disso foi acidente. A sonho petista para o futuro do Brasil, que agora se desmancha no ar, é Dilma Rousseff esmurrando a mesa e gritando “Belo Monte vai sair!” para sempre.

Commentary
The Racist and Politically Motivated Origins of the War on Drugs

In the cover story of this month’s Harper’s Magazine, author Dan Baum recounts a conversation he had with former Nixon domestic affairs adviser and convicted Watergate co-conspirator John Ehrlichman. Baum states that in 1994, Ehrlichman told him that the Nixon Administration started the War on Drugs as an attack on black Americans and anti-war protesters.

Baum quotes Erlichman “The Nixon campaign in 1968, and the Nixon White House after that, had two enemies: the antiwar left and black people… …We knew we couldn’t make it illegal to be either against the war or black, but by getting the public to associate the hippies with marijuana and blacks with heroin, and then criminalizing both heavily, we could disrupt those communities.

He specifically mentioned noted that under such policies “We could arrest their leaders, raid their homes, break up their meetings, and vilify them night after night on the evening news.” Erlichman may be referring to the no-knock searches permitted under the Comprehensive Drug Abuse Prevention and Control Act of 1970, which allowed law enforcement to search homes unannounced. On a related note another former Nixon aid, Roger Ailes continues the demonization of black and young people “night after night” on his network Fox News.

Three additional Nixon aides have denied that Erlichman would have said such things and have instead suggested that Baum had misunderstood Ehrlichman’s use of sarcasm. Even if their allegations are correct, Baum’s overall point that the Nixon administration pursued policies that encouraged intrusive searches, arrests and stigmatization of its political opponents, still stands. Nixon’s use of enemies lists, wiretaps and other “dirty tricks” is well established. Such tricks included COINTELPRO tactics, which involved federal agents infiltrating anti-war and black power groups, creating infighting and getting the leaders addicted to drugs. Against this backdrop it is hard to believe the War on Drugs was not politically motivated.

Motives aside, the real consequence of such policies has been to disrupt and greatly harm black and young people, just as Baum depicts Erhlichman as suggesting. Sadly the general trend for subsequent presidents has been to continue and the drug war to the extent that it has now become the classic example of a failed policy, not unlike the prohibition of alcohol during the 1920s. Drug prohibition has created violent drug cartels, gang violence, a massive prison population and millions of wasted tax payer money, not to mention the wealth that would be generated if the drug trade were legal.

A better approach would be stop punishing people for so-called “crimes” that in no way harm another person. We should have the full freedom to use our bodies as we please provided we do not hurt others in the process. After fifty years we should no longer be embracing Nixonian policies, with their legacy of dishonesty, racism and violence. Nor do we need puritanical politicians and authoritarian moral guardians telling us how to live our lives. Countries like Portugal have benefited from ending their drug wars, while US states are moving away from Marijuana prohibition. The decriminalization of more drugs will inevitably follow. Let’s make the end of prohibition come sooner rather than latter. It’s not a war on drugs, its a war on personal freedom.

Commentary
Brazil’s Media was Always Pro-Government

The repeated denunciations of the “coup media,” which supposedly favors the impeachment (a “coup,” in the government’s supporters language), is interesting because it shows how short everyone’s memories are (“Novos discursos, o mesmo golpismo“, Carta Capital, April 4; “Deputado Paulo Pimenta publica roteiro de golpe jurídico-midiático em 13 passos“, Jornal do Brasil, March 25). Nobody remembers that this same media was infatuated with Dilma Rousseff by mid-2012. Who remembers the editorials by Veja, Folha de São Paulo, and Estadão brown-nosing the president in the first 100 days of her administration? Who remembers the Época magazine’s extra edition crawling after the government after the 2010 election? Who remembers IstoÉ magazine’s giving Dilma the “Brazilian of the Year” award in 2011? Who remembers the “Dilmachinist,” as she was portrayed in humor TV shows? And what about the spaghetti she prepared on daytime TV? The media wasn’t anything if not obsequious for a long time.

During Lula’s first term Congress vote-buying scandal, she was shielded by the press. The order of the day was to bury the old Workers’ Party (PT) and save the new Workers’ Party. That despite the fact that the “new” and “modern” PT was deeply involved with the whole corruption scheme.

The most symbolic episode was the so-called “ministry clean-up” in Dilma’s second term. Dilma had sold a dozen ministries to rotten politicians in the hopes of getting support during her election campaign. To get rid of them, she started leaking information to the media so they would be forced to renounce. During these series of corruption scandals, the media — especially the largest TV network, Globo — created the fantastical narrative in which the ministries’ corruption and the president had nothing to do with each other. On the contrary, she was promoting a clean-up in the government. I remember being flabbergasted by the construction of this lie of a honest president surrounded by corrupt ministers. Dilma was the Bonapartian hero cutting loose the Gordian knot of the Brazilian coalition presidentialism. She was Dilma the broom, sweeping away the dirt in the hallways of power. It was basically the same idiocy that led Globo to support Collor’s presidency more than 20 years ago. It was then that rumor had it that powerful Globo editor Ali Kamel had been neutered in their journalism division to celebrate the new arrangement with the presidency.

It later became clear that this clean-up was very particular, for it replaced mice with bigger rats — only this time they were rats closer to the president. In the Ministry of Transportation, for instance, after the “sweeping” changes, the bribes were raised from 4% to 8%. Globo soon collected her end of the bargain in 2014, when it commissioned the Homeric beating of the president during the first question of the live interview with the president from Brazilian during the Jornal Nacional (the prime time newscast in the country), which dealt with corruption and ministry reform.

The content put out by the press only really changed after the protests of June 2013. Veja then published a headline saying that “the streets message is clear: it’s time to govern” — which sounds ridiculous when you consider that the magazine swooned over or stayed silent about the government for two years. That’s the greatest irony: the first sign of discontent came from the streets when the “coup media” worked for the government.

Before you tell me I’m crazy, I’m not the one saying all those things. The left is. Rodrigo Vianna, a journalist who left Globo in 2006 and became of of these paid mouthpieces of the regime, published an article in 2012 stating the same.

It wasn’t only the media that adored Dilma. Everyone did. She reached 80% approval ratings. The moldy right-wingers were ecstatic: Dilma didn’t talk to the social movements, didn’t care for the Natives who lived in the Xingu River Basin, didn’t have any interest in land reforms. She liked hydroelectric dams and shooting rubber bullets at protesters. She was basically our old military dictator Ernesto Geisel in a skirt.

But, after all, who spoke up against the government? The usual suspects: the economists. Mansueto Almeida, ever since the government campaigned for the opening of a tablet computer manufacture in the country (today that sounds ridiculous, but years ago everyone thought it was a leap into the future), said that the industrial policy of the government was anachronistic and that the country was becoming more and more closed off. Alexandre Schwartsman was fired from Santander because he insisted that the government was using state oil company Petrobras to forge a fiscal balance. Celso Pastore kept saying that the government was manipulating exchange rates to contain price levels. Fabio Giambiagi wrote over and over that consumption and debt had reached their limit and could not sustain growth.

For many, the misery Brazil finds itself in nowadays has been a long time coming. The media the left insists always wanted to oust the government, on the other hand, was taken by surprise.

Translated by Erick Vasconcelos.

Commentary
Laws Won’t Keep Bathrooms Safe

(CW: Discussions of transphobia and sexual abuse)

The Washington Post recently reported on a South Carolina bill introduced by Senator Lee Bright who claims, “I don’t believe transgender people are pedophiles,” but, “I think grown adult men would use this as protection to violate women in the restroom.”

Like many others, Bright fails to understand that non-discrimination laws aren’t meant to protect against assault nor do they need to. In states where non-discrimination laws have been instituted, men who use them as an excuse to harass or assault women would still be legally liable for their actions.

Besides, there are many laws that all of us “take advantage of” every single day, harming others in the process. This harm doesn’t automatically make the intent behind the law wrong-headed and it doesn’t mean we should punish those who had nothing to do with the harm by depriving them of their rights. In other words, the transgender community shouldn’t suffer the consequences of pedophiles and sexual predators, especially not if you claim you don’t think they are those kinds of people.

The Post also notes that when U.S. Attorney Bill Nettles was asked about cases in which transgender folks verbally or physically assaulted others, he responded simply, “I can find none.” Nettles also noted that South Carolina already has laws to address “assault and battery.” This response, while helpful, doesn’t go far enough.

Arguments for discrimination against transgender individuals often presume that laws make us safe. But ultimately what keeps people from harming each other is their own internal sense of right and wrong. A ubiquitous though minor example is jaywalking.

Individuals will abridge or ignore the law altogether so long as doing so won’t harm other people. This is a commonsense approach that people have taken on much larger scales; for instance, widespread use of marijuana despite its illegality.

If cis people want to be safer from predators, they need to understand that most predators aren’t dressing up so they can assault people. They’re much more likely to be people you know. And if you’re worried about strangers and children, the US Justice of Department reports that only 10% of sexual predators are strangers to the victim-child.

Those concerned with safety under non-discrimination laws should also consider the general safety of the transgender community.

ThinkProgress cites a study by the Williams Institute in 2013 focusing on transgender folks, which concluded, “an overwhelming majority — 70 percent — had experienced some sort of negative reaction when using a bathroom.”

These reactions included verbal harassment, denial of restroom use, and even physical assault in 9% of the cases.

ThinkProgress says that all of this occurred “in spite of the fact that DC’s enforcement regulations contain ‘the strongest language in the country in regard to gender-segregated public facilities’ to protect trans people from just these sorts of issues.”

Neither Bright’s law nor non-discrimination laws are guarantees of safety. In fact, nothing is a guarantee of safety. All we can hope to do is optimize relative safety, but the state is hardly the best tool to do that. The overwhelming majority of safeguards people rely on are of the non-state variety. The state is the organization that has historically been captured by privileged groups to oppress marginalized ones — so safety seems like the antithesis of what’s offered by the state.

Campaigns that unify transgender and allies like #IllGoWithYou are much more effective at providing safety. That’s because these forms of solidarity rest on local and individual knowledge about their communities and personal circumstances. This gives people an edge when responding to transphobia in their lives, far more so than relying on the state’s malleable pieces of paper.

Laws are made by bureaucrats, largely if not entirely cis, who have little to no experience with the oppression that trans people face. So even when the “best” sorts of laws are made by the state they are often woefully unprepared to tackle oppression that we as trans folks are confronted with every day.

For the trans community in particular the state has been wholly inadequate in defending our rights.

And at worst it’s been our enemy.

Let’s never forget that.

Portuguese, Stateless Embassies
Golpismo? A mídia sempre foi adesista

O linchamento da “mídia golpista” (“Novos discursos, o mesmo golpismo“, Carta Capital, 4 de abril; “Deputado Paulo Pimenta publica roteiro de golpe jurídico-midiático em 13 passos“, Jornal do Brasil, 25 de março) é interessante porque nessas horas fica claro como as pessoas tem a memória curta. Ninguém se recorda que essa mesma mídia golpista estava totalmente apaixonada por Dilma em meados de 2012. Quem lembra dos editoriais da Veja, da Folha de São Paulo e do Estadão puxando o saco da presidente nos primeiros 100 dias de mandato? Quem lembra da edição extra da Época se arrastando nos pés do governo depois da eleição? Quem se lembra da IstoÉ dando prêmio de “Brasileira do ano” pra Dilma em 2011? Quem se lembra da “Dilmaquinista”? Do espaguete que ela preparou no programa da Ana Maria Braga?

Até durante o julgamento do mensalão ela foi blindada pela imprensa (mais ou menos na mesma época da capa ridícula do “choque de capitalismo” e da “Dilma fala à Veja”). A ordem do dia era enterrar o PT velho e salvar o PT novo, o PT moderno, apesar de esse PT moderno estar enfiado até o pescoço na articulação do governo Lula quando todo escândalo aconteceu.

Sem dúvida o episódio mais simbólico foi na época da “faxina ministerial”. Dilma tinha vendido uma dezena de ministérios pra políticos podres em troca de apoio durante a eleição e depois, pra se livrar deles, começou a vazar informações para a mídia para forçar a renúncia desses ministros. Durante essa série de denúncias de corrupção a mídia — e especialmente a Globo — criou a narrativa fantasiosa de que a corrupção nos ministérios e a presidente não tinham nada a ver um com o outro. Pelo contrário, Dilma estava promovendo uma “faxina” ministerial. Eu lembro de ter ficado meio pasmo com a construção dessa mentira da presidente honesta cercada de ministérios corruptos. Dilma era a heroína bonapartista que estava cortando o nó górdio do presidencialismo de coalizão no Brasil, a Dilma vassourinha, que limpava a sujeira dos salões do poder. Basicamente a mesma idiotice que levou a Globo a bancar a candidatura de Collor. Foi nessa época que surgiu o rumor que Ali Kamel tinha sido neutralizado na direção de jornalismo da Globo pra celebrar o acordo com a presidência.

Depois começou a ficar claro que essa faxina era meio peculiar porque ela tirava um rato e colocava uma ratazana muito maior, só que mais próxima a ela — como aconteceu no Ministério dos Transportes, quando depois da “faxina” a taxa da propina subiu de 4% pra 8%. A Globo cobrou a conta em 2014, quando encomendou a surra homérica logo na primeira pergunta da entrevista feita ao vivo em Brasilia com a presidente no Jornal Nacional, justamente sobre a corrupção e reforma ministerial.

O teor da cobertura da imprensa só começou a mudar depois das manifestações de junho de 2013. A Veja publicou uma edição com a chamada afirmando que “o recado das ruas indica que está na hora de governar” —  o que soa patético se você considerar que a revista puxou o saco ou ficou muda sobre o governo durante dois anos. Essa é a grande ironia: o primeiro sinal de revolta contra o governo veio das ruas quando a “mídia golpista” só conspirava a favor.

Antes que digam que eu estou delirando, quem afirma que Dilma estava casada com a mídia não sou eu, é a própria esquerda. Rodrigo Vianna, aquele jornalista que saiu da Globo em 2006 e depois se tornou uma dessas bocas pagas do governo, publicou um artigo em 2012 dizendo o mesmo.

Não era só a mídia que adorava Dilma, todo mundo adorava. Ela chegou a 80% de aprovação. A direita mofada estava em êxtase: Dilma não conversava com movimento social, não queria saber de índio de Xingu, ela não estava interessada em reforma agrária. Ela gostava mesmo de hidrelétrica e de borrachada em manifestante. Era praticamente um Geisel de conjuntinho.

Mas afinal quem foi que se manifestou contra? Economistas, aqueles mesmos suspeitos de sempre. Mansueto Almeida, desde a época da histeria pela instalação da fábrica de tablets no Brasil (hoje soa ridículo, mas anos atrás todo mundo achava que era um salto para o futuro), já falava que a política industrial do governo era anacrônica, que o país tava cada vez mais fechado. Alexandre Schwartsman foi demitido do Santander porque insistia que o governo estava usando a Petrobrás pra maquiar superávits. Celso Pastore vivia dizendo que o governo manipulava câmbio e usava estatais pra conter nível de preços. Fabio Giambiagi cansou de publicar artigos dizendo que consumo e endividamento já tinham chegado no limite e não iam mais sustentar crescimento.

Pra muita gente a fossa em que o país está hoje é uma tragédia anunciada, mas pra mídia golpista foi uma surpresa.

Stigmergy - C4SS Blog
Richman Discusses New Book on Free Association

C4SS Senior Fellow and Trustee Chair Sheldon Richman recently spent some time on Free Association talking with Lucy Steigerwald about his newest book, America’s Counter-Revolution: The Constitution Revisited. Some of the topics discussed include the Federal Convention, the Constitution, the Articles of Confederation, the Federalists, and the Anti-Federalists.

The talk is about an hour in length.

Books and Reviews
Panarchist Anthology Published

A new anthology titled Panarchy: Political Theories of Non-Territorial States, edited by Aviezer Tucker and Gian Piero de Bellis, has been released by Routledge.

panarchy-cover

The concept of panarchy comes from an 1860 work of that title by the Belgian botanist and political economist Paul Émile de Puydt (1810-1891). The essence of his panarchist proposal is that people should be free to choose the political regime under which they will live without having to relocate to a different territory. The new anthology assembles a number of sources, both historical and contemporary, developing this idea.

The editors define panarchism as “a normative political meta-theory that advocates non-territorial states founded on actual social contracts that are explicitly negotiated and signed between states and their prospective citizens.” (p. 1) This characterisation, with its call for explicitly signed contracts, is a somewhat narrower use of the term than is common in contemporary anarchist circles, or at least those in which I move. John Zube, who has done more than anyone to popularise the concept, defines it a bit less rigidly as the “realization of as many different and autonomous communities as are wanted by volunteers for themselves, all non-territorially coexisting … yet separated from each other by personal laws, administrations and jurisdictions ….” (quoted on p. 90)

If one’s standard for political legitimacy is efficiency, wouldn’t the competition of multiple systems within the same jurisdiction be more efficient, for familiar economic reasons, than the imposition of a single model? If one’s standard is what rational agents could consent to, why not support a system in which everyone gets the system they actually consent to? After all, part of the point of the hypothetical consent stories that have dominated contemporary political philosophy is the assumption that actual consent could never be unanimous — an assumption that panarchism shows how to circumvent. If the worry is that competing systems within the same territory would be unworkable, a number of the pieces in the volume point out how, in Aviezer Tucker’s words, “there have been many historically functioning models of mixed, overlapping, and extra-territorial … jurisdictions” (p. 148) — or, in Richard C. B. Johnsson’s formulation, for most of human history “laws followed the persons, not the territory.” (p. 207)

The various contributions to the volume make a fascinating and, to me, compelling case. (Self-promotion alert: I have a chapter in the book, one of my pieces from the 1990s advocating “virtual cantons.” In the interests of further disclosure, one of the editors, Tucker, is a friend; I recall with fondness a long hike with him down Prague’s Petřín Hill, in the course of which his daughter learned to walk.)

Left-libertarians should be warned, however, about occasional passages that will make their jaws drop, such as Max Borders’ cheery assurance that “if police are cruising your neighborhood, you’ll benefit” (p. 174), or Michael Gibson’s equally cheery assurance that large corporations, despite their “visibly dictatorial” structure, are “not poorly behaved at all.” (p. 167) Perhaps these writers are from a parallel universe?

Amazon currently lists the print edition of the book at over $100, and the Kindle edition at over $50. So I can’t in good conscience urge anyone to buy the volume. Urging you to recommend it to your local academic library is another matter, however.

In what follows I address three more specific issues.

Panarchism and Anarchism

Is panarchism a form of anarchism? Certainly it’s often so regarded. De Puydt himself appears to have envisioned a monopoly apparatus administering the various social contracts, but more recent panarchists have generally dispensed with this element; and even de Puydt included “Proudhon’s anarchy” on the list of political options among which citizens could choose (though how the nonexistence of the monopoly apparatus could be one of the options offered by the monopoly apparatus is something of a mystery).

While granting that the distinction may, at least in some cases, be “semantic rather than substantive,” Tucker is inclined to distinguish anarchism from panarchism, for the following reasons. (Incidentally, Tucker takes anarcho-capitalism in particular to accept some notion of territorial sovereignty, which seems to me to be in most cases a misinterpretation.) To begin with, panarchism demands “voluntarism … in the choice of social contracts,” but has “nothing to say about the contents of contracts,” which “may be highly coercive”; thus while anarchists typically reject “states and institutions that are based on authority, hierarchy, domination, and coercion,” panarchy as Tucker conceives it allows people to contract into “states with coercive powers” that “force their citizens to do things they do not want,” and even licenses a “Hobbesian social contract” in which citizens “give up all their civil rights in return for the state’s guarantee of physical safety.” (p. 9)

Judging from this passage, Tucker does not appear to countenance the idea of inalienable rights – that is, rights that cannot be surrendered in contract. But this is not a point on which panarchists are unanimous. Michael Rozeff, in his contribution to the volume, writes that those who “choose a Government” can “choose to leave a Government.”

They need only retain the option to exit in their choice of government. But persons actually cannot give up that option. They cannot voluntarily give up their wills. (p. 91)

De Puydt himself took an intermediate position between complete freedom of exit and irrevocable self-alienation:

I do not suggest one should be free to change one’s government at any time, causing it to go bankrupt. For this sort of contract between states and citizens one must prescribe a minimum term, say one year. (p. 34)

But if one takes the Rozeffian option of complete freedom of exit, then it’s not clear that the anarchist has any reason to reject the legitimacy of contracting oneself into a dictatorship, since a dictatorship that one can leave at any time is merely like bondage using safe words. A slave with a safe word is no slave at all. And the idea of free experimentation with different systems of rules has been embraced by many anarchists, of both communist and market varieties. (On this point, see Kevin Carson’s recent C4SS study Anarchists Without Adjectives: The Origins of a Movement.)

More broadly, for Tucker anarchism and panarchism must be at odds, because panarchism allows people to “associate and dissociate with states voluntarily,” while anarchism “opposes the very existence of states.” (p. 12) For those accustomed to the Weberian definition of the state as a territorial monopoly of force, this might seem puzzling; if the political entities that panarchists advocate are not territorial monopolies, why call them “states,” or suppose that the anarchist rejection of states must apply to them?

Part of the reason, it seems, is that Tucker does not accept the Weberian definition. He writes:

The Greek polis was essentially a structure of people united by law, not by a relation to a territory. When the Greeks colonized, the future state, the polis, its hierarchical political structure, had already existed on the ship, before a favorable precise site was chosen. (p148)

This is a fair point; but I’d want to make two caveats. First, while the Greek polis may not have been a territorial monopoly, it was certainly a monopoly (over a given population); and second, it always ended up in fact claiming and exercising jurisdiction over a particular territory. In both respects it resembles modern states in a way that competing panarchist regimes do not.

In reply, Tucker would presumably point to the “division of power between the church, the king, and the vassals” in medieval Europe, as well as the “extra-territorial arrangements of mixed sovereignty … in the Ottoman and Chinese empires” (p. 149), as examples of (things we call) states that were not monopolies, territorial or otherwise. Again, a fair point; but I would still insist that these states they were much more like territorial monopolies than are the regimes that panarchists propose. People born into a medieval king’s territory often had a choice as to whether to use a royal court, a manorial court, an ecclesiastical court, or a merchant court, but for the most part they had no choice as to whether or not to be subject in general to the king’s authority. The Ottomans allowed Christians to be governed by Christian rather than Muslim law, but this was a grant of privilege from a territorial ruler who determined the content of the concession. And so on.

In short, then, I would resist calling the panarchist’s political regimes “states”; and I have no problem regarding panarchism, at least in its modern form, as a species of anarchism.

Neglected Precursors

The contributors to the volume identify a number of historical precursors to their ideas. One is de Puydt’s countryman Gustave de Molinari, whose 1849 proposal for competing security agencies is included; another is the anarchist historian Max Nettlau, whose 1909 essay on the subject is also included. Another example, a surprise to me, is Moritz Schlick, the founder of logical positivism. (p. 12) Sadly, his work on the subject – unfinished since, as Tucker rather euphemistically puts it, Schlick “died prematurely” (he was shot by a disgruntled student) – is not included.

There are other precursors that might have been mentioned in the book, but are not. Perhaps the earliest panarchist proposal, albeit made in jest, occurs in Aristophanes’ Acharnians, whose central protagonist, an Athenian citizen, claims the right to decide his own foreign policy, both military and economic, rather than following that of Athens as a whole. A less favorable treatment occurs in Plato’s Republic, in which Athens is described, rather implausibly, as a “supermarket of constitutions” where each citizen can live under whatever regime he likes, regardless of what choice his fellow-ciitzens make. (On panarchist ideas in Aristophanes and Plato, see my recent essay on the subject.)

Another unnoted panarchist precursor is the German idealist Johann Gottlieb Fichte, who defended a right of individual secession in his not-yet-fully-translated 1793 tract Contribution to the Rectification of the Public’s Judgment of the French Revolution. But this is perhaps an unwelcome precursor, given the work’s repulsive – and rhetorically self-defeating – antisemitism. (Rhetorically self-defeating, because Fichte’s ostensible aim in mentioning the Jews is to point to them as a successful example of a non-territorial political community, and so his immediately taking the opportunity to indulge in an antisemitic rant hardly aids his purpose.)

The idea of individual secession was revived independently by Herbert Spencer in his 1850 Social Statics, specifically in his chapter “The Right to Ignore the State” – though while he allows citizens to sever relations with their former state without a change of territory, he does not envision the possibility of their signing up with a competing service provider.

Much closer is the American individualist anarchist Benjamin Tucker, who in 1887 wrote:

There are many more than five or six Churches in England, and it frequently happens that members of several of them live in the same house. There are many more than five or six insurance companies in England, and it is by no means uncommon for members of the same family to insure their lives and goods against accident or fire in different companies. Does any harm come of it? Why, then, should there not be a considerable number of defensive associations in England, in which people, even members of the same family, might insure their lives and goods against murderers or thieves?

(Tucker incidentally takes the side of Rozeff against his homonym on the question of inalienability, maintaining that “no man can make himself so much a slave as to forfeit the right to issue his own emancipation proclamation.”) Tucker’s disciple Stephen Byington agreed, pointing to the fact that in Kansas City, the state line “runs right through the edge of the city, among popular streets,” so that “[m]en who live on the same street are subject to different laws.” (Byington also mentions the exemptions for Christians in Muslim countries.) Another Tucker disciple, Francis Tandy, held similar views.

Economic Justice

There is one objection to panarchism that I suspect will be widely raised, especially by Rawlsian liberals, and I don’t think it gets much discussion in the book. That objection is that panarchism is economically unfair.

“You want a redistributive state?” Rich Ralph asks Poor Petunia. “Go ahead and sign up for one. But my rich friends and I are all going to sign up for something else. Have fun redistributing wealth among your impoverished pals, but count us out.”

At this point the Rawlsian liberal says: “Look, Ralph: you and your rich friends, and Petunia and her poor friends, have all been part of the same society-wide cooperative endeavor for mutual advantage; they’ve brought you your caviar nachos, you’ve paid their salaries, and so on. We need to ask whether the fruits of that cooperation are being fairly distributed, or whether the situation has been objectionably exploitative. For you to simply pull out and thus declare yourself exempt from the redistributive laws that Petunia and her friends want to pass is rather too much like a thief declaring that he’s going to sign up with a regime that says theft is okay (or at least that theft by members of that regime against members of other regimes is okay) so he’s not bound by the anti-theft laws that his victims want to pass. You can secede from their authority, but they can’t secede from the externalities you’re dumping on them.”

There are a number of different ways that a panarchist could respond to the Rawlsian liberal, but I suspect the most effective would be to show, along the lines that left-libertarians have suggested, that it’s precisely the absence of panarchy (or in other words, the presence of a monopoly state) that is chiefly responsible for the economic disparity with which the Rawlsian is concerned. However, this would require taking sides on issues that at least some panarchists seem to want to remain neutral on, such as the comparative merits of left-libertarian and right-libertarian economic analysis.

Feature Articles
How Do You “Get Over” Something That’s Still Going On?

You’ve probably had one of Those People say (usually after sidling up to you, looking around to see if anybody’s listening, and prefacing it with an “I’m not racist, but…” disclaimer) “Slavery was 150 years ago — they need to get over it!” Or maybe it’s ethnic cleansing episodes like Tulsa (“90 years ago”), or segregation (“50 years ago”). But one way or another, I’m sure you’ve heard it. Well, as it turns out Hillary Clinton is one of Those People. She actually said it in the context, not of American slavery, but of Western imperialism in Africa. And she didn’t whisper it after scouting out eavesdroppers, because it never occurred to her that a liberal like her could be one of Those People.

Clinton, in a speech as Secretary of State to a diplomatic forum on Africa back in 2010 (“Clinton: Africa must launch tough economic reforms,” Reuters, June 14, 2016), took a tone with Africa similar to that Bill Clinton took with Black Lives Matters activists in regard to the 90s crime bill and welfare reform and his wife’s “super-predator” comments. In other words, she basically said it’s time to stop coddling Africans and show them some tough love (sounds almost like Marvin Olasky, doesn’t she?). Specifically, Africans need to let go of the past and stop whining about the economic legacy of imperialism. “For goodness sakes, this is the 21st century. We’ve got to get over what happened 50, 100, 200 years ago and let’s make money for everybody.”

The problem is, Western imperialism isn’t something that ended “50, 100, 200 years ago.” I’d be interested in knowing what Clinton considers the last act of imperialism in Africa. The assassination of Patrice Lumumba (assuming that event even exists in her universe)? No — Western imperialism in Africa — like the structural legacy of slavery in the US — never stopped.

Apparently Clinton isn’t familiar with the concept of neo-colonialism, which points to the continuities between the present-day activities of Western governments and global capital in the former colonial world and the power relationships that existed under colonialism. The main difference is that the Third World is now nominally “independent,” and the responsibility falls on local governments to enforce Western capital’s rights to extract mineral wealth and engross land, and keep local sweatshop labor in line. And Western “foreign aid” and World Bank loans, as Kwame Nkrumah remarked decades ago, are what would have been called “direct foreign capital investment” under plain old colonialism.

If local governments are insufficiently enthusiastic in enforcing the rights of transnational corporations, the capitalist world’s second line of defense is IMF structural adjustment plans and other forms of discipline by “multilateral bodies.” And if all else fails, if someone like Mossadegh or Lumumba or Arbenz tries to return the stolen oil, mineral wealth and land to the people, there’s always the US military and CIA.

Just look at South Africa. Nelson Mandela was spirited from prison to an isolated English manor house for face-to-face talks with representatives of the Apartheid state and the world’s major mining companies, at which he was offered a pardon and a referendum on black majority rule — if, that is, the ANC would abandon its project of taking back those mines that had been developed with slave labor. Or look at the blood-soaked “conflict minerals” in your iPhone, extracted from Congo; the symbiosis between local mercenaries and Western corporations there is a direct continuation of events going back to the assassination of Lumumba and US support for Mobutu. Look at the mercenaries and death squads in Nigeria, funded by Shell Oil.

The irony is that we need only look at Clinton’s “economic reform” proposals for Africa for proof that imperialism is an ongoing phenomenon. She wants African nations to adopt a neoliberal legal regime that facilitates continuing Western extraction — looting — of their resources. When she talks about “structural reforms” and “lowering customs barriers,” it’s not even code — she flat-out means falsely so-called “Free Trade Agreements” like TPP (which she promoted as Secretary of State, and has developed temporary reservations about until after the election). In other words, it has nothing at all to do with free trade. It’s about enforcing the highly coercive and protectionist legal regime which allows global corporations to keep right on extracting wealth from Africa.

It’s about enforcing existing corporate titles to the stolen mines and oil wells. It’s about enforcing the titles of landed oligarchs and agribusiness corporations to enormous tracts of land that were stolen from peasants to grow cash crops on. It’s about enforcing the patents and trademarks that enable Western corporations to outsource production to sweatshops that pay starvation wages, while using their monopoly on disposal of the product to mark up retail prices at Walmart a thousand percent over production cost. It means “intellectual property” provisions in those so-called “Free Trade Agreements” that punish government offices and schools for using free software. It means punishing countries that allow production of generic forms of life-saving AIDS drugs.

In other words, what Clinton wants is the opposite of free trade. She wants to keep the wealth of Africa in hands of the heirs and assigns of the same people who stole it, under colonialism. She wants to enforce the monopolies that continue to squeeze the life blood out of Africa — literally, in the case of preventing competition in the supply of AIDS drugs. Imperialism didn’t happen a hundred years ago. In economic terms, the colonial conquest of the world was never undone — the victors still own the resources and markets of the world. Clinton wants to make sure they keep right on doing so.

Clinton complains about the “special interests” who oppose her neoliberal agenda. And when she says “special interests,” she’s not talking about  the corporations that own the mines and oil wells, that fund the mercenaries who disrupt Congo, that hold the patents on life-saving drugs. But these are the special interests that have the blood of millions on their hands, and continue to murder every day.

Yes, Africa certainly does need free trade, if “free trade” simply means eliminating tariffs. Africa also needs free trade that includes abolishing legal monopolies like “intellectual property,” abolishing the thieves’ artificial title to stolen land and returning it to its rightful peasant owners, and taking the mines back from the slavers and genocides and giving them to the people whose sweat and blood built them. These things would all be genuine free trade. They would all be genuine economic reform. And they’re all things Clinton would commit mass murder to stop.

Commentary
How Clinton Encouraged Obama’s Biggest Blunder

Barack Obama recently said that his biggest blunder was “failing to plan for the day after” his intervention in Libya. While he defended the intervention itself, the president cannot deny that his reckless war has had disastrous consequences, including a growing ISIS presence in Libya.

Hillary Clinton eagerly pressured the president to overthrow Moammar Gaddafi. Former Defense Secretary Robert Gates recalls that, “The president told me that it was one of the closest decisions he’d ever made, sort of 51-49, and I’m not sure that he would’ve made that decision if Secretary Clinton hadn’t supported it.”

After overthrowing Gaddafi, Clinton proclaimed triumph, saying “We came. We saw. He died.”

The U.S. intervention killed a dictator, but it certainly didn’t bring freedom or security to Libya. As Alan Kuperman explains, “Libya has not only failed to evolve into a democracy; it has devolved into a failed state.”

In that failed state, militias and terrorists fight a bloody civil war, with ordinary Libyan citizens caught in the crossfire. While Obama and Clinton sold the war as a humanitarian intervention, Libyans don’t seem to be better off in this violent and chaotic environment.

ISIS forces took advantage of this chaos to gain a foothold in Libya. So in addition to failing to protect Libyan civilians, Clinton and Obama undermined American national security interests. Kuperman writes, “Libya today is riddled with vicious militias and anti-American terrorists — and thus serves as a cautionary tale of how humanitarian intervention can backfire for both the intervener and those it is intended to help.”

Hillary Clinton stands by her decision, calling the Libyan intervention “smart power at its best.” But as Christopher Preble of the Cato Institute says, “If this is smart power at its best, I would hate to see it at its worst.”

This isn’t the first failed war Hillary Clinton supported. She infamously voted for the 2003 invasion of Iraq. That foolish war created a power vacuum and plunged Iraq into a civil war. Over 3,529 American soldiers died in combat. Over 156,492 Iraqi civilians were killed, according to Iraq Body Count.

After all those deaths, was America more secure? On the contrary, ISIS was only able to rise to power because of the power vacuum left by the American invasion.

While more blood and treasure was lost in Iraq than Libya, both interventions undermined American security.

President Obama recognizes this, but still defends the Libyan intervention itself, arguing that his “failure to plan for the day after” explains the disaster.

Would more planning have solved the problem? Foreign countries are complex, and wars cause unpredictable chaos. U.S. officials do not have enough knowledge to plan entirely new institutions and governance under these conditions.

The world is unpredictable and complicated. Wars create unintended consequences. When George W. Bush invaded Iraq, he caused a bloody civil war, thousands of civilian deaths, and set the stage for ISIS. When Barack Obama overthrew Gaddafi, he lengthened a bloody civil war, created a failed state, and gave ISIS a foothold in Africa.

Hillary Clinton recklessly supported both of these interventions. Rather than planning for the day after, she encouraged poorly planned wars that unleashed chaos and undermined security at home and abroad.

Leaders should be wary of war and cautious about intervening in complex foreign affairs. Wars squander taxpayer dollars, spread violence, and kill innocent civilians. The costs are clear. But the promised benefits, whether humanitarian or security-oriented, may never materialize. War often exacerbates humanitarian crises and undermines national security.

It is prudent to exercise caution and restraint in foreign affairs. Hillary Clinton shows no restraint. Instead, she recklessly promoted two of the most disastrous wars in recent memory.

Center Updates, Stigmergy - C4SS Blog, Supporter Updates
Media Coordinator Report, February and March 2016

These are the numbers and a few interesting bits on our work in February and March:

February

March

General comments:

  • We had a slight drop in pickups these last two months, dipping below the 3 pickups average I set out to maintain. Mea culpa. I’ve already added 100 new outlets to our list of recipients so I can balance that out!
  • We’ve kept with our theme of publishing 20 or more of articles in a month, and that’s awesome!
  • Augusta Free Press and NewsLI are still our most consistent partners, picking up most of our content.

This is just a little bit of what we’ve been doing. With your help, we can do even more to spread the word of markets and anarchism. Please donate via PayPal or our several other methods!

Erick Vasconcelos
Media Coordinator

Portuguese, Stateless Embassies
Minha opinião anarquista sobre os Papéis do Panamá

A liberação dos Papéis do Panamá há pouco mais de uma semana — registros de onze milhões de documentos da firma de advocacia Mossack Fonseca — mostra como os maiores bancos globais movimentam os ativos de capitalistas bilionários e de grandes figuras políticas para fora de seus países para protegê-los dos impostos. A revelação mexeu em muitos vespeiros em todo o mundo. O governo islandês deve cair e seu parlamento deve ser tomado por uma maioria do Partido Pirata devido às revelações. A carreira do primeiro-ministro britânico David Cameron pode estar ameaçada. E eu duvido que os trabalhadores reais no paraíso dos trabalhadores da China estejam felizes em saber que os líderes do Partido Comunista têm levado seus bens roubados para dentro de paraísos fiscais.

Enquanto anarquista, obviamente eu não tenho perdido muito sono ao pensar que os estados nacionais estão perdendo arrecadação por conta desses fatos. Eu mesmo já negociei descontos várias vezes com muitos comerciantes para pagar minhas compras em dinheiro e ambos ficamos muito satisfeitos com o acordo. Uma das vantagens de arranjos informais dentro da economia social é que a troca direta de trabalho por trabalho dribla os custos do estado burocrático.

Mas o que é diferente neste caso?

Primeiramente, a principal função do estado é a de servir aos plutocratas que têm enviado para fora suas riquezas para evitar os impostos. O estado subsidia as grandes empresas, erguendo barreiras de entrada, restrições competitivas e protegendo direitos de propriedade artificiais como a “propriedade intelectual”, permitindo a existência dos rendimentos de monopólio que alimentam os plutocratas. Como afirma Noam Chomsky, o capitalismo corporativo é a socialização dos custos e a privatização dos lucros. Todas essas ações são bancadas pelos impostos. Considere esse fato ao avaliar o relatório recente que afirma que 74% das fortunas dos bilionários advém de rendimentos obtidos com a ajuda do estado (e eu considero essa uma estimativa muito conservadora).

Até mesmo as ações “progressistas” executadas pelo estado servem para manter o capitalismo sobre uma base estável no longo prazo, maximizando a taxa sustentável de exploração. A maior parte dos benefícios assistenciais do estado — como aposentadorias, bolsas e outros auxílios — são financiados pelos próprios favorecidos através de impostos sobre a folha de pagamento ou são iguais aos custos daquilo que os ricos causaram ao resto da população.

E, além disso tudo, as próprias classes que controlam o estado, que se beneficiam de seus subsídios e de sua proteção dos rendimentos de monopólio, pegam as riquezas extraídas da população e as movem para o exterior. Isso é parte — uma parte particularmente perversa — de uma tendência mais ampla das últimas três ou quatro décadas de neoliberalismo, em que o ônus dos impostos tem sido transferido para os salários dos trabalhadores, aliviando os retornos sobre propriedades acumuladas.

Ou seja, essa aplicação seletiva das leis tributárias em favor das próprias classes servidas pelo estado cheira muito mal.

Contudo, mais importante do que confirmar minha opinião extremamente negativa sobre os ricos e poderosos, a liberação dos Papéis do Panamá me dá grandes esperanças. Eles representam, como afirmou o título de um artigo do Guardian de Micah White, o “amadurecimento do ativismo de vazamentos“. Se os vazamentos de Chelsea Manning em 2010 e de Edward Snowden em 2013 foram pequenos passinhos, os Papéis do Panamá sinalizam o que podemos esperar com os vazamentos futuros.

E, como Glyn Moody afirma no Techdirt (“Terabyte-Sized ‘Panama Papers’ Leak Confirms The Continuing Rise Of The Super-Whistleblowers“, 4 de abril), um vazamento dessa magnitude não seria possível cinco anos atrás — mas é viável agora, graças à disponibilidade de pen drives de um terabyte.

Lembro de minha euforia quando ocorreu a liberação dos documentos da HBGary e da Stratfor e minha esperança de que estivéssemos entrando em um período em que toda semana veríamos uma bomba atômica de informação dessa magnitude derrubada sobre uma corporação da Fortune 500. Mas também lembro de minha tristeza quando o FBI prendeu o hacker Sabu e o núcleo do grupo LulzSec.

Mas finalmente está acontecendo de verdade — só que dessa vez através dos esforços de vazadores internos, não por causa de hackers de fora. Tenho aquela sensação que tive em 2011. Quem vai ser o alvo da semana? Shell? Monsanto? Nestlé? O FBI? A RIAA? Seja o que for, não acho que vá levar muito tempo até que eu veja versões reais dos cenários descritos por Ken MacLeod em Cosmonaut Keep e por John Brunner em The Shockwave Rider, onde todas as iniquidades das instituições poderosas eram expostas.

É bom estar vivo.

Feature Articles, The Weekly Abolitionist
Prisons and Primitive Accumulation

One important point my colleague Kevin Carson has emphasized repeatedly is that the prevailing labor relations in our society are not just a natural outgrowth of voluntary exchanges in a free market. Instead, they have resulted from pervasive state intervention that constrains the options of workers, thus leaving them in a worse position to bargain with employers. Drawing on Marx, he notes that the position of wage laborers was particularly influenced by the enclosure of the commons and the resulting dispossession of peasants from their ancestral lands. Marx called this process primitive accumulation, and famously wrote that “these new freedmen became sellers of themselves only after they had been robbed of all their own means of production, and of all the guarantees of existence afforded by the old feudal arrangements. And the history of this, their expropriation, is written in the annals of mankind in letters of blood and fire.”

This process was not a one time event that occurred in the transition from feudalism to capitalism. Instead, it is an ongoing process, seen in the news even today.

Historically, incarceration has played an important role in this process. This should not be surprising. After all, incarceration is one of the primary techniques of state violence, and states controlled or influenced by employers will likely be used to impose work discipline.

One prominent example of the use of prisons to impose work discipline is the criminalization of African American life in the South after the Civil War. The Black Codes provided a variety of restrictions that exclusively applied to blacks, many of which were directed at imposing work discipline. Many of these laws were intended to coerce freed blacks into labor conditions very similar to those they had faced on slave plantations. For example, according to the Constitutional Rights Foundation:

The South Carolina code included a contract form for black “servants” who agreed to work for white “masters.” The form required that the wages and the term of service be in writing. The contract had to be witnessed and then approved by a judge. Other provisions of the code listed the rights and obligations of the servant and master. Black servants had to reside on the employer’s property, remain quiet and orderly, work from sunup to sunset except on Sundays, and not leave the premises or receive visitors without the master’s permission. Masters could “moderately” whip servants under 18 to discipline them. Whipping older servants required a judge’s order. Time lost due to illness would be deducted from the servant’s wages. Servants who quit before the end date of their labor contract forfeited their wages and could be arrested and returned to their masters by a judge’s order. On the other hand, the law protected black servants from being forced to do “unreasonable” tasks.

Other criminal law provisions of the Black Codes were used to pressure blacks into accepting these contracts. For example, vagrancy laws criminalized unemployment, gambling, peddling, and other forms of “idleness.” They also heavily restricted economic opportunities outside of these hierarchical options. Economist Jeffrey Rogers Hummel notes that “South Carolina forbade them from practicing any profession other than servant or agricultural laborer.” These restrictions on economic liberty limited labor mobility and bargaining power, forcing black workers to accept conditions that they would never tolerate in a freed market.

An article in the Marxist magazine Jacobin argues that the Black Codes were a textbook case of primitive accumulation:

One of the key features of primitive accumulation is the use of direct coercion until the wage-labor/capital relationship is naturalized — at which point Marx’s famous “dull compulsion of the economic” takes over. The political struggle, at least for a brief time, during Reconstruction was whether emancipation would mean real liberation — Jim Crow settled the question securely in favor of former plantation owners, and the criminal law was the central instrument through which wage-labor was instituted.

Freed blacks may have wanted to pursue any manner of economic activity to support themselves, independent of the bosses who used to call themselves slave owners. But the state, through its criminal justice system, ensured that couldn’t happen.

One doesn’t need to be a Marxist to recognize that incarceration has played a major role in imposing work discipline throughout history. For example, free market economist Bruce Benson, in his anarcho-capitalist classic The Enterprise of Law, describes how one of the first uses of English prisons was imposing work discipline:

“Houses of correction” were first established under Elizabeth to punish and reform able-bodied poor who refused to work. A “widespread concern for the habits and behavior of the poor” is often cited as the reason for the poor laws regarding vagrancy and the establishment of facilities to “reform” the idle poor by confining them and forcing them to work at hard labor. But Chambliss reported that “there is little question but that these statutes were designed for one express purpose: to force laborers (whether personally free or unfree) to accept employment at a low wage in order to insure the landowner an adequate supply of labor at a price he could afford to pay.” Such laws clearly reflected the transfer function of government.

By forcing the poor to work at low wages, prisons were used to transfer wealth from workers to politically connected land owners. The Black Codes played a similar transfer function for politically connected plantation owners and other white employers.

Primitive accumulation is far from the only function of incarceration. Today, mass incarceration does not so much enforce work discipline as it punishes black market entrepreneurship and excludes felons from the formal labor market, both through discrimination by employers and through licensing laws that prohibit felons from participating in a wide range of occupations.

But the history of incarceration as a tool to impose work discipline is important. It reminds us that government often redistributes wealth upwards by repressing workers to the benefit of employers. And when we understand that, we can understand why struggles against poverty and exploitation are intimately tied to struggles for liberty.

Commentary
My Anarchist Take on the Panama Papers

The release of the Panama Papers last weekend — a paper trail of eleven million leaked documents from the Mossack Fonseca global law firm — shows how major global banks move assets of billionaire capitalists and major political figures offshore to protect them from taxation. The revelation has stirred up a political hornets’ nest all over the world. The Icelandic government is probably going to fall and its parliament swept by a Pirate Party majority because of the revelations. UK Prime Minister David Cameron’s career may well be on the line. And I doubt the actual workers in the workers’ paradise of China are real pleased to learn the leaders of the, ahem, Communist Party have been moving their stolen loot into tax havens.

As an anarchist, I’m obviously not losing much sleep over the idea of state taxing authorities losing revenue. I’ve done plenty of business with hardworking tradespeople on a cash discount basis, and we were entirely happy with the arrangement. One of the benefits of informal arrangements within the social economy is that the direct exchange of labor for labor avoids the overhead of feeding the bureaucratic state.

So what’s different about this case?

For starters, the state’s main function is to serve the very plutocrats who have been offshoring their wealth to avoid taxation. It subsidizes big business out of the general revenue. It enforces entry barriers, restraints on competition and artificial property rights like “intellectual property,” enabling all the monopoly rents that those plutocrats live on. Corporate capitalism, as Noam Chomsky says, is socialized cost and privatized profit. And the cost of doing all these things is funded by coercive taxation. Consider this in the light of a recent report that some 74% of billionaires’ wealth (and I consider that a very conservative estimate) comes from rents obtained with the help of the state.

Even the “progressive” stuff the state does is for the purpose of keeping capitalism on a long-term stable basis and maximizing the sustainable rate of exploitation. And most of it  — old age pensions, welfare, food stamps — is either funded by the recipients themselves through payroll taxes, or amount to the capitalist state funding cleanup costs for what the rich have done to the rest of us.

What’s more, the very classes that control the state, and benefit from its subsidies and enforcement of monopoly rents, turn around and move their ill-gotten “privatized profit” offshore. This is part — an unusually ugly part — of a much larger trend, over the past three or four decades of neoliberalism, of shifting the main burden of taxation onto the wages of labor and off of returns on accumulated property.

So yeah — this selective enforcement of the tax laws, in favor of the very classes served by the state, stinks to high heaven.

But more important than confirming my low opinion of the rich and powerful, and giving me some entertainment, the story gives me hope in a big way. The Panama Papers represent, as the title of an article by The Guardian‘s Micah White puts it “leaktivism’s coming of age” (April 5). If leaks by Chelsea Manning in 2010 and Edward Snowden in 2013 were the gigantic “baby steps,” the Panama Papers are a sign of what we can expect as leaktivism matures.

And as Glyn Moody points out at Techdirt (“Terabyte-Sized ‘Panama Papers’ Leak Confirms The Continuing Rise Of The Super-Whistleblowers,” April 4), a leak on this scale wouldn’t have been possible five years ago — but is now, thanks to terabyte-scale thumb drives.

I remember my exhilaration at the doxxing of HBGary and Stratfor, and my hope that we were entering a period where every week would see a similar information H-bomb dropped on a new Fortune 500 corporation. And I remember my sadness when FBI busted Sabu and the core of the LulzSec group.

But maybe it’s finally happening for real — only this time through the efforts of inside leakers rather than outside hackers. I’m getting that feeling I had back in 2011. Who’s going to be the lucky target this week? Shell? Monsanto? Nestle? The FBI? The RIAA? Whether this is it or not, I don’t think it will be long before we see a real-life version of the scenarios in Ken MacLeod’s Cosmonaut Keep and John Brunner’s  The Shockwave Rider, where all the iniquities of powerful institutions are dragged into the light of day.

It’s a good time to be alive.

Stigmergy - C4SS Blog, Weekly Libertarian Leftist Review
The Weekly Libertarian Leftist Review 117

Jacob G. Hornberger discusses the blindness of conservatives.

Doug Bandow discusses Donald Trump and the neoconservatives.

Lucy Steigerwald discusses the folly of war.

Micah Zenko discusses the Libyan war.

Glenn Greenwald discusses double standards on victims of violence.

Barret Brown discusses the authorized biography of Henry Kissinger.

Sheldon Richman discusses what terrorists want.

Dan Sanchez discusses how Muslims are standing up to extremism.

Richard M. Ebeling discusses third way politics.

Stephen Kinzer discusses the situation in Honduras.

Laurence M. Vance discusses whether joining the military is the right thing to do or not.

Lew Rockwell discusses why Bill Buckley conservatism is dead.

Richard M. Ebeling discusses what progressives don’t get about liberty.

Dan Sanchez discusses imperial sacrifice in Yemen.

Jonathan Cook discusses Israeli military culture.

Ivan Eland discusses why more Western meddling in Libya is a bad idea.

Doug Bandow discusses why the U.S. can’t be the world’s nuclear police.

Jacob G. Hornberger discusses the evil of sanctions.

Jacob Sullum discusses the federal ban on pot ads.

Andrew J. Baevich discusses Ted Cruz, foreign policy, and conservatism.

George H. Smith discusses Ayn Rand’s intellectual influence on him.

Roderick T. Long discusses Aristophanes’s comedy.

Uri Avnery discusses Israeli relations with the Arab states.

Laurie Calhoun discusses the Canadian govt acquiring military grade drones.

Andrew J. Bacevich discusses presdential power and war.

Andrew J. Bacevich discusses the unwinnable war for the Middle East.

Dan De Luce and Paul Mcleary discuss Obama’s drone strike policies.

Ramzy Baroud discusses BDS.

Justyn Dillingham discusses a book on Allen Dulles.

Stigmergy - C4SS Blog
America’s Counter-Revolution: The Constitution Revisited

America’s Counter-Revolution: The Constitution Revisited

Authored by Sheldon Richman
Foreword by Jeffrey A. Tucker

This book challenges the assumption that the Constitution was a landmark in the struggle for liberty. Instead, Sheldon Richman argues, it was the product of a counter-revolution, a setback for the radicalism represented by America’s break with the British empire. Drawing on careful, credible historical scholarship and contemporary political analysis, Richman suggests that this counter-revolution was the work of conservatives who sought a nation of “power, consequence, and grandeur.” America’s Counter-Revolution makes a persuasive case that the Constitution was a victory not for liberty but for the agendas and interests of a militaristic, aristocratic, privilege-seeking ruling class.

New.jpg

About the author:
Sheldon Richman is a senior fellow of the Center for a Stateless Society (c4ss.org), chair of the Center’s trustees, and a contributing editor at Antiwar.com. He is the author of three other books:Separating School and State: How to Liberate America’s Families (1994); Your Money or Your Life: Why We Must Abolish the Income Tax (1999); and Tethered Citizens: Time to Repeal the Welfare State (2001), published by the Future of Freedom Foundation (fff.org). From 1997 to 2012 he was the editor of The Freeman, published by the Foundation for Economic Education (fee.org), following which he edited Future of Freedom for the Future of Freedom Foundation. Previously he was an editor at the Cato Institute, the Institute for Humane Studies, and Inquiry magazine. Richman’s articles on foreign and economic policy, civil liberties, and American and Middle East history have appeared in Newsweek, The Washington Post, The Wall Street Journal, theChicago Tribune, the Chicago Sun-Times, USA Today, Reason, Forbes, The Independent Review,The American Scholar, The American Conservative, Cato Policy Report, Journal of Economic Development, Journal of Palestine Studies, Washington Report on Middle East Affairs, Middle East Policy, Liberty, and other publications. He is a contributor to the The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Richman is a graduate of Temple University in Philadelphia. He blogs at Free Association (sheldonrichman.com).

Anarchists Without Adjectives
Dyer Lum — Anarchists Without Adjectives

Download a PDF copy of Kevin Carson’s full C4SS Study: Center for a Stateless Society Paper No. 21 (Spring 2016)

Anarchists Without Adjectives: The Origins of a Movement

Introduction

Errico Malatesta

Joseph Labadie

Dyer Lum

Voltairine De Cleyre

Max Nettlau

The Question of Anarcho-Capitalism

Conclusion

About all of any substance that James J. Martin has to say about Dyer Lum, despite his being “one of the most interesting and important figures in the American anarchist movement,” fills a total of about half a page in Men Against the State. Lum

established relations with both its major wings during a hectic ten years of association, but always remained close to the individualist philosophy. … His career as a participant in the labor movement grew out of his reflections on the Pittsburgh riots during the 1877 railroad strike, but before Haymarket had swung over to the extreme left position of the anarchists and mutualists, impressed with the possibilities of cooperation in economics.

Following the arrest of Parsons in Chicago, Lum revived the Alarm late in 1887, changing much of its editorial policy to fit in line with that of Liberty, in which he had been writing for some time. Henceforth he carried on in the interests of the individualists, dwelling especially on the occupation and use land tenure, and the mutual bank money ideas, in works of his own and in the journals of others. Along with Tucker, he expressed the conviction that force was not necessary to effect a revolution, nor was there any proof that its use was even generally successful. [14]

Beyond this, the material on Lum below comes largely from Frank H. Brooks’s article on his thought. [15]

Dyer Lum was by far the most labor-friendly of the individualists. Like Labadie, he tried to bridge the gap between Tucker’s circle and the labor movement. And like Voltairine de Cleyre, he also tried to bridge the gap between native individualists and immigrant communists and syndicalists. Like Tucker and the other individualists, Lum came from the general culture of New England reformism, and participated in many of its currents before he arrived at anarchism. He was involved with the Labor Reform Party in the 1870s, and worked as a bookbinder and labor journalist. From this involvement he made connections with the Greenback Party and the eight-hour movement. Under George’s influence he blamed the U.S. government’s land grants to corporations and its restrictions on homesteading for much of labor’s dependent position. From the Greenback Party, Lum moved on to the Socialist Labor Party in 1880, and by the mid-80s was involved in the International Working People’s Association. But unlike most others in the International, Lum analyzed capitalism from a radicalized laissez-faire perspective much like that of the individualists.

Heavily influenced by Proudhon, Lum gravitated toward a mutualist theory of economics closer to mainstream Proudhonianism than to Tucker’s individualism. Accordingly, he had a vision of anarchist unity much like de Cleyre’s. His economic views were an unusual combination of laissez-faire and the Chicago labor movement’s hatred of the “wages system.” He perceived that the electoral disasters of the Socialist Labor Party and Greenback-Labor Party had left a leadership vacuum in the radical labor movement, that could be filled by anarchists if they were smart enough to make their message relevant to labor.

From 1885 on, as Brooks described it, Lum tried to fuse “working-class organization, revolutionary strategy, and mutualist economics” into a united radical movement “designed to make anarchism a magnet to radicalized workers.” He did not wish to unite the various groups behind any dogmatic party line, but only to create ties of affinity between them and enable them to work together tactically in “a pluralistic anarchistic coalition.”

Lum rounded out his economic vision with the principle of producer cooperation, not only at the level of artisan production, but in large-scale industrial associations. In the latter regard he viewed labor unions not only as a weapon against existing evils, but as the nucleus of a future industrial organization formed around the “associated producers.”

In the post-Haymarket atmosphere, the anarchist movement was torn by dissension as individualists like Tucker reacted harshly to their perceived differences with immigrant communists. Nevertheless Lum continued to hope for improved relations between the two camps. He met de Cleyre in this period.

In the 1890s, he placed increasing stress on “inoculating trade unions with anarchist principles.” He became closely associated with the AFL and was on Gompers’s personal staff. His pamphlet The Economics of Anarchy was designed to introduce workers’ study groups to mutual banking, land reform, cooperation and other mutualist practices. He also supported the Homestead and Pullman strikes, and the wave of strikes that led to the formation of Haywood’s Western Federation of Miners.

Lum deserves much credit for fusing so many disparate strands of radicalism into a uniquely American ideology. He tied a radical vision of working class power to a fairly sophisticated understanding of classical and mutualist economics, framed — like de Cleyre’s pamphlet “Anarchism and American traditions” — in terms of traditional American populist symbols.

Lum, in the meantime, had on his own adapted a tolerant position, treating matters of economic system as secondary to the elimination of the state. [16]

And as de Cleyre was to do in “Anarchism and American Traditions,” Lum appealed to the radically libertarian republicanism of the Revolution, especially to the rhetoric of Paine and Jefferson, as precursors to the native populist strands of anarchism.

Dyer Lum, according to Hippolyte Havel’s biographical sketch, was also “undoubtedly the greatest influence in shaping [De Cleyre’s] development.” [17] That’s the perfect segue into the next section.

Notes:

12. Axel B. Corlu, “LABADIE, JOSEPH A. (1850-1933),” Encyclopedia of U.S. Labor and Working Class History, Vol. 1. Eric Arneson, ed. (New York and London: Routledge, 2007), p. 760.
13. Ibid., p. 245n; the full context can be found in his Cranky Notions column in the April 14, 1888 issue Liberty <http://fair-use.org/liberty/1888/04/14/cranky-notions>. Accessed February 16, 2016.
14. Ibid., pp. 259-60.
15. Frank H. Brooks, “Ideology, Strategy and Organization,” Labor History 34:1 (1993).
16. Martin, pp. 150-151.
17. Hippolyte Havel, “Introduction,” Selected Works of Voltairine De Cleyre, edited by Alexander Berkman (New York: Mother Earth Publishing Association, 1914), p. 12.

Commentary
Prisons Don’t Bail Out the Poor

The New York Times recently reported that on March 13th, Jeffery Pendleton was found dead in his jail cell. Pendleton was a homeless man who lived in New Hampshire and had been arrested on March 8th for outstanding fines and possession of small amounts of marijuana. His set bail of $100 was prohibitively costly for him and he was left to languish in his cell until trial, over a month later.

According to New Hampshire’s state experts, there were no sign of foul play.

Pendleton’s family disagrees, saying on a GoFundMe campaign that aims to bring Pendleton’s body home: “His body has been viewed by a second source and we have found that we were lied to by the medical examiner in New Hampshire as well as the jail. … The second report completed in Arkansas states there are clear indications that Jeffery was harmed prior to his death and likely that harmed caused his death.”

Pendleton’s death, whether a freak accident or something more, reflects a disturbing trend of individuals, particularly lower-income and people of color, dying in jail cells. Another high-profile victim, a black woman named Sandra Bland, died after only three days in jail in 2013. Her death was ruled a suicide but her family, like Pendleton’s, disagreed.

In practice, jails tend to work as places where lower-income people must be processed and held until they can be processed again. As Gilles Bissonnette, a director for the American Civil Liberties Union of New Hampshire said of Pendleton’s case, “at that point, he would have effectively served his sentence before he ever had an opportunity to contest the charge — an outcome that only a poor person would be confronted with.”

The issue of prohibitively high bail is serious enough that the Department of Justice (DoJ) released an official statement around the time of Pendleton’s death. Such statements don’t have the force of law, but they can influence shifts in policy by making the federal government’s position clear on a given issue.

At one point the statement says “[b]ail that is set without regard to defendants’ financial capacity can result in the incarceration of individuals not because they pose a threat to public safety or a flight risk, but rather because they cannot afford the assigned bail amount.”

As such, jails are often used as pre-detention centers that skirt around Constitutional requirements of “fair and equal treatment” under the law. If poor people are regularly locked up and have bail set without regard to their ability to pay then equality under the law seems like an unlikely outcome.

But even if we tried to make bail set partly on the basis of financial stability and well-being, this would not be enough. Whether it comes to police and civil forfeiture, the criminal justice system and plea deals, or the prison industrial complex, the state’s profit motive leads them to seek monopoly profits to the disadvantage of the accused and convicted.

As the New York Times notes, this report by the DoJ, “…echoes the conclusions of the Justice Department’s investigation of the Police Department and court in Ferguson, Mo. Investigators there concluded that the court was a moneymaking venture, not an independent branch of government.”

But “independence” is a meaningless term when the government has created and reinforced perverse incentives that treat individuals as a stream of revenue. Fixing that isn’t going to be accomplished by sending letters to courts and politely asking them to change. In fact, the way to affect change isn’t to ask nicely for the government to play by its own rules. We’ve been doing that for too long to no avail.

It’s time we made up our own rules and played by them ourselves in peaceful and creative ways. This means building alternative forms of dealing with crime that don’t rely on punishment being the focus of rehabilitation. It also means not treating money as the sole way that people can help atone for their offenses.

But of course, Pendleton didn’t do anything wrong.

Well, besides being poor.

Portuguese, Stateless Embassies
Portuguese Media Coordinator Update: February and March 2016

Este é meu primeiro relatório de coordenação de mídias e estes são nossos números em fevereiro e março:

  • Facebook: 4311 curtidas (+68)
  • Twitter: 125 seguidores (+5)
  • Tumblr: 31 seguidores (+0)

Publicamos dois artigos inéditos neste período e buscamos divulgamos o conteúdo desenvolvido pelo Centro por intermédio da republicação diária de textos de nosso repositório. Nos próximos meses, tentaremos aumentar um pouco mais nossa produtividade.

Se você gosta do nosso trabalho, pode apoiar nossos esforços mundiais para espalhar as ideias anarquistas fazendo uma doação pelo PayPal ou por várias outros meios que disponibilizamos.

Diogo Ladeira Sales
Coordenador de Mídias Sociais em Português
Centro por uma Sociedade Sem Estado

Portuguese Media Coordinator Update: February and March 2016

This is my first media coordinator update and these are our numbers for February and March:

  • Facebook: 4311 likes (+68)
  • Twitter: 125 followers (+5)
  • Tumblr: 31 followers (+0)

We published two new articles in this period and we also managed to promote content put out by C4SS over our last year. In the next few months, we will try to increase our productivity a little bit.

If you appreciate our work, you can support our worldwide efforts to spread the word of anarchy by making a donation via PayPal or our several other options.

Diogo Ladeira Sales
Portuguese Media Coordinator
Center for a Stateless Society

Stigmergy - C4SS Blog
Instead of a Book, by a Man too Lazy to Write One

I’ve been writing at my site Abolish Work for a few years now and I’m really encouraged by all of the support that’s come in so many different shapes in sizes. That support has given me the confidence to reach out to Little Black Cart, an anarchist publisher whose books C4SS has reviewed many times, regarding a proposal for an anti-work anthology.

I’m happy to report not only that Little Black Cart accepted my proposal, but also that my book is fully underway and will likely be published in 2016. Its title, Instead of a Book, by a Man too Lazy to Write One, is inspired by Benjamin Tucker.

I have many articles, blog posts and essays designated for the book, but I’m always interested in more.

If you’d like to contribute to the book, the deadline for submissions is May 1st with a 1000-2000 suggested word-limit. Some categories that’ll be covered include the relationship between individualist anarchism and work, reviews of anti-work media such as books or movies and commentaries on news stories from an anti-work perspective.

For those confused, anti-work doesn’t mean “anti-effort.” By work, all I mean is a type of constrained labor that individuals engage in, not for their own sense of self, but because of some sort of external reward, usually money. Much of work in the current economy is made up of individuals who feel underappreciated, uninvolved and generally uninterested in whatever they’re doing. They do what they do because they need the money but once they get the paycheck they couldn’t be happier to be as far away from whatever they were just doing for most of their day.

These are the sorts of relationships I think should be abolished. Instead, I think we should move towards a world where play is more central and people are better able to express their individuality and do what makes them feel fulfilled.

If these ideas appeal to you then please feel free to reach out to me with submission ideas.

Happy slacking!

Commentary
Bernie Sanders’s Short Memory

During his interview with the New York Daily News, Bernie Sanders was asked to specify the fraud committed by Wall Street banks. He replied:

“What kind of fraudulent activity? Fraudulent activity that brought this country into the worst economic decline in its history by selling packages of fraudulent, fraudulent, worthless subprime mortgages. How’s that for a start?

Selling products to people who you knew could not repay them. Lying to people without allowing them to know that in a year, their interest rates would be off the charts. They would not repay that. Bundling these things. Putting them into packages with good mortgages. That’s fraudulent activity.”

Does Sanders really forget that it was progressives like him who demanded that banks lower lending standards so that low-income people with no, weak, or bad credit histories could get mortgages with low teaser interest rates that would later balloon? Is he ignorant of the fact that these banks had every reason to believe the government would bail them out if they failed? Does he not recall Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, the government-sponsored enterprises championed by Barney Frank and other progressives, that were right in the middle of this action, knowing they’d be saved if they failed? Has Sanders no memory of mortgage lenders like Countrywide, which were celebrated by progressives for aggressively pushing mortgages on people who could not afford them? Is he unaware that HUD, under Bill Clinton (and Secretary Andrew Cuomo) as well as George W. Bush, enabled people with poor credit and low incomes to “buy” houses with little or no down payment? And finally, is he oblivious of the fact that it was all these government-pushed shaky mortgages that were bundled into the exotic investment instruments Sanders now decries?

I’m pretty sure Sanders is aware of all this. But it doesn’t fit his narrative that the Great Recession was entirely the result of private-sector greed, so he can’t acknowledge it. Wall Street is properly viewed with suspicion, but what makes that reasonable is that it has long been in cahoots with the national government, notably with federal deposit insurance, which rewards irresponsibility by relieving depositors of the need to judge banks’ sobriety or lack thereof.

In other words, Sen. Sanders, Wall Street couldn’t have done it alone. It needed people like you.

(For more details see Peter Boettke and Steven Horwitz, The House that Uncle Sam Built.”)

Anarchy and Democracy
Fighting Fascism
Markets Not Capitalism
The Anatomy of Escape
Organization Theory